Frances Bula header image 2

Developers to mayors/councils: We give you millions for community benefits, you take the credit

July 25th, 2013 · 29 Comments

One Twitter follower asked if I was writing for the Onion with this story in the Globe, so I guess the snark brigade will be out in full force here. Would be nice to have a more thoughtful discussion about developer contributions — do they deserve more acknowledgement or is their contribution in fact a pretty minimal tax on their profits, as I know some will think?

 

Published Monday, Jul. 22, 2013 10:15PM EDT

 

Last updated Tuesday, Jul. 23, 2013 11:20AM EDT

 

Developers are growing increasingly exasperated that they get little or no credit for huge contributions they make to everything from culture to parks to daycares in the Lower Mainland – contributions increasingly required by area cities.

“The fact is that the development community does a ton and makes a huge contribution to all kinds of social benefits,” said Dana Westermark, president of Oris Development Corporation. Mr. Westermark did a slow burn recently when a news story about Richmond announcing $4.3-million for “cultural-history projects” didn’t mention he provided that money as part of his London Landing project.

It’s not the first time. “We did a very large project with the city, built a neighbourhood utility project for the Alexandra neighbourhood,” he said. “They crowed about what a fantastic thing they had done without acknowledging our part.”

Mr. Westermark is hardly the only unhappy developer. The region’s development-industry association says the failure to mention industry contributions is a pattern in many cities, one it is determined to fight.

Urban Development Institute “is fully prepared to challenge any ‘fluffy’ press announcements by municipal officials/mayors/councillors regarding public amenities paid for in part or whole by [fees charged to builders] and which do not properly and fairly reference the development industry,” said one recent internal e-mail from the institute to its members. The institute provided a series of announcements from Vancouver demonstrating the problem.

Institute president Anne McMullin said the lack of credit is not just a case of well-off developers having hurt feelings. The public perception that developers don’t contribute affects cities’ ability to talk about planning or growth in neighbourhoods. “The public just sees the change in their community and they don’t see the public benefits,” she said.

As a result, she said, there’s uproar in communities where either individual projects are proposed or where cities are creating new planning frameworks for whole areas – like Vancouver’s Grandview-Woodlands – because it’s not spelled out what those communities are getting back.

In Vancouver, which extracts the most from developers of any municipality in the region, even the signs set up around new projects announcing what is planned for that plot of land don’t spell out what the developer is contributing – even though it’s typically something substantial.

“You need to do that right from the get-go so the community knows the benefit,” Ms. McMullin said.

According to provincial government statistics the UDI has dug out, developers paid $634-million last year to various municipalities through what are called developer cost charges – DCCs, for short.

Developers in an increasing number of municipalities also pay a second layer of fees, called community-amenity contributions.

Vancouver has been at the forefront of those – charging $180-million last year – but suburban municipalities that have become the sites of high-density projects are starting to charge them too.

Vancouver’s general manager of planning, Brian Jackson, said he concurs that the city has not done a good enough job of acknowledging developer contributions. That’s critical, because those contributions are not just extras – they’re essential.

“In delivering the kinds of ambitious amenities people want, we can only do it now with the assistance of the private sector,” he said.

Mr. Jackson said the city is starting a process to collect information on how much developers have paid for in the city to help make the public more aware. He also said that when the four city neighbourhood plans are being finalized this fall – plans that generated some backlash over proposals for much higher-density development – there will be specifics that show exactly what benefits at what price neighbourhoods will get in return.

“We need that so the public does understand how growth finances community benefits,” he said.

In Richmond, Councillor Bill McNulty, who made the recent announcement about the $4.3-million in cultural projects the city is financing, said he is never shy about giving developers credit.

“I always give them full marks,” he said. “Without development, a lot of things we get credit for would never happen.”

The problem, he says, is that even when the politicians do give developers credit, that doesn’t get passed on by the people who tell the story – those news reporters who don’t provide the full picture.

 

 

Categories: Uncategorized

  • neil21

    I assume / hope your readers follow Chuck Marohn at Strong Towns. Part of his thesis is that big developers are just churning out a product that sells, so they can bundle and flip to MBS dealers on wall street. Instead good, fine-grained urbanism that we’d all like to live near and walk past is built by many individuals over time. Chris Leinberger has some good work on the 19 securitisable types of real-estate.

    I think many would like Vancouver’s tax base to be built from many small projects, whose ongoing property tax revenue is sufficient to sustainably fund our amenities.

    Instead we seem to have a handful of large developers who make big one-off contributions – in a non-transparent way (are they paying enough? by what metrics?) – to upzone. This often pits large developer (wants short-term profit) and city (wants short-term contribution) against the community (wants long-term nice place to live / walk past).

    In my opinion, a transparent form-based code (zoning by transect; quick & cheap – i.e. same-day & <$1000 – approval for development proposals that meet code) would be a big help in this. Community plans are too wordy (lets see a 3D model on the web of the whole area today, and as permitted) and often too ambiguous.

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    CACs are not paid by developers, Frances, they are passed along to the homebuyers and are part of the answer to why we are seeing sky-rocketing house prices.

    Mount Pleasant’s Implementation Committee drew up their own plan to show the city what Mount Pleasant people want Mount Pleasant to be like. We dubbed it “Small Is Beautiful” just so everyone knows what we’re talking about:

    http://wp.me/p2FnNe-8f

    The Rize in Mount Pleasant is the going example of how the system is broke and we have to fix it. The private sector runs on the bottom line, as it should, so we need to look for solutions elsewhere.

    A monstrosity is being foisted on the first neighbourhood to develop outside the downtown. It is now all-‘luxury condo’ with wrap around retail. No business space in Mount Pleasant’s downtown. Go figure. A historic nightclub (which I never attended) is going to be turned into underground parking. Oh, yes! There is no public space either. Plaza hovers above the (dirty) street below. Historic Watson Street’s being fed to the lions of the development industry. The project’s a roaring success!

    Nice bargain for somewhere north of $6 million in CACs. A sum that will be parsed and collected from each and every condo sale inflating the price.

    Where has all the affordable housing gone, Frances?

    If we give our neighbourhoods away there is not going to be anything left to fight for. Need to change the paradigm before the Vancouver we love is lost and gone forever.

    We need social housing; affordable housing; walkable neighbourhoods; livable streets; BRT on the street now (trolleys are parked at the transit centre with nowhere to deploy); park space; neighbourhood retail; incubator space for local businesses; stronger schools…

    Time to change paradigm. The old one has run out of fossil fuel, the new has legs.

  • Morven

    On balance, transparency by municipalities is a desireable outcome. It is not the present situation.

    But I would point some questions to the municipal accountants who should not be able, at a stroke of a pen, to comingle DCC funds on paper with taxation income.

    If not, as cities, we are merely behaving as if the DCC is a medieval “indulgence”. And in doing so, there is no across-the-board consistency.

    I think the developers have a reasonable point to make.
    -30-

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    Neil, we cross-posted. Dig it! City wide transect-code; build-out model. Tower zones are clearly identified; so are neighbourhood centres; neighbourhood edges; and neighbourhood middles. Suburban, rural and undisturbed wild habitat round out the scene.

  • Warren

    Lewis, CACs are not the cause of high housing prices. That’s completely false.

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    If you don’t believe CACs are being passed down to the consumer, then let me sell you a bridge. Re-zoning land to luxury condo is contributing by fuelling speculation.

  • Randy Chatterjee

    Telling the “full story” of the economic or political side of Community Amenity “Contributions” (CAC) risks upsetting a hugely overloaded apple cart, and I am certainly glad I didn’t start this conversation. Nor will I finish it. Thank you, Frances.

    Let’s first be clear that outside of Vancouver, and maybe a few wannabe neighbouring municipalities, no other cities on earth have a formalized development “tax” keyed to land lift. I call it a tax, because there is an explicit–albeit not transparent–formula of some 80% of the increase in “land life” or project value from a rezoning. Said tax and value are of course subject to “negotiation,” which is code for the applied discretion of City staff. Many attempts at forensic audits of these payments show extremely high variability in the implied tax rate.

    Of course, we cannot call this a “tax,” as it would be illegal under Common Law, federal and provincial tax legislation, and the Vancouver Charter. It is a of course a voluntary “donation.”

    But let’s leave tax lawyers out of it and be clear from an economist’s perspective just what is occurring. Most development taxes are proportional, fee-based payments related singularly and linearly to the square footage built, i.e. Development Cost Levies (DCLs, or DCCs in other jurisdictions). These often vary by geographic area or zoning within a city, but they are predictable and directly proportional to the size of the development and thus the sale or lease value of the building.

    Predictability is key, as the functioning of a free market depends upon it. All market players face the same costs and thus compete on level ground. Such fees are priced both into the value of land and land-with-improvements. Every city has also a different rate, in part as a means of competing for development, paying for infrastructure, encouraging growth, and building amenities.

    Now imagine another form of development tax, a form of ad valorem “windfall profits” scheme, that applies a variable, negotiated rate to the imputed profit from a range of development outcomes. The CAC is just such a squirrelly beast, and like a squirrel it goes many places you might not like.

    A developer prices and buys a building lot with exactly no idea what may be allowed to be built there, nor how long it will take to secure permission. Uncertainty #1. And please note that Zoning Bylaws, District Schedules, Design Guidelines, lot-specific Regional Growth Strategies, Regional Context Statements, Official Development Plans, and Community Plans are ALL of little or no help. They are ALL “guidelines.” A CD-1 rezoning is highly unpredictable, highly political, and highly variable in outcome, at least for most developers.

    And then there is Uncertainty #2. Assuming a developer gets City Staff and Council majority support for what he or she wants for building use, type, style, height, and square footage, what’s due?

    Well, that depends. It depends upon how much was paid for the land and how long it’s been held, the agreed cost of construction (including contractual, scheduling, and geotechnical uncertainties), the assumed unit sales prices and net present value of lease payments, and even the financial risk assessment that prices the cost of capital to fund the construction. So, the developer must now start meeting with the City Real Estate Department, BEFORE a building is even proposed, to negotiate some hypothetical profits tax based on so much uncertainty that anyone’s head would spin.

    The bottom line of course is that the development will not proceed and no CAC at all (or even the proportional fees, DCLs) will be collected by the City if no deal is struck. And the more apparent market value created and the higher the project leverage or risk, the more “tax” is assessed. The City’s incentives are to push the envelope on size and profitability (and thus the imputed land value lift), and the developer’s entry and carrying costs are so high that they must be spread over more saleable yield despite the exponentially higher risk.

    In the academic world of objective decision analysis, this situation goes by a name that cannot be published, and goes by the acronym CF.

    The outcome of such extreme market uncertainty to any economist is clear: extremely high fixed costs, high barriers to entry, and highly variable and temporally volatile returns. This looks almost exactly like the mining industry, and perhaps this is no surprise given where we are.

    But the highest cost is not in extreme market distortion (high land values) or economic inefficiency (high development costs), but it is political. The “free market” does not run this system, but rather political influence. No “democratic” model of governance can survive an economic system that rewards only the deepest pockets with huge reserves of capital AND political influence, and punishes everyone else.

    This development system has to go, and we can look ALL over the world to find a better one. One new acronym: TIF. Not perfect, but much better.

  • Jonathan Baker

    The problem with Community Amenity Contributions (CACs) is that they result from an adhoc process of negotiation and therefore represent the sale of zoning. It like a Persian Market. The City only can make money from developers when they rezone. If the developer is held to the zoning bylaw no amenity payment is required.

    The City makes money by selling extra height or density or use to the developer i.e. by departing from its own regulations. The burden of the development is transferred to the neighbours whose properties are either overshadowed or affected in some other way. The affected neighbours are the ones who should be compensated – not the city. The amenity contribution does not even have to benefit those neighbours.

    This is completely different from development cost charges.

    Jonathan Baker

    Jonathan Baker

  • Jonathan Baker

    The problem with Community Amenity Contributions (CACs) is that they result from an adhoc process of negotiation and therefore represent the sale of zoning. It like a Persian Market. The City only can make money from developers when they rezone. If the developer is held to the zoning bylaw no amenity payment is required.

    The City makes money by selling extra height or density or use to the developer i.e. by departing from its own regulations. The burden of the development is transferred to the neighbours whose properties are either overshadowed or affected in some other way. The affected neighbours are the ones who should be compensated – not the city. The amenity contribution does not even have to benefit those neighbours.

    This is completely different from development cost charges.

    Jonathan Baker

  • Ian

    Randy, Great post, but just a quick follow-up to say that Toronto has a very similar land-lift based development “tax” in their section 37 agreements. It’s not as high a % of the lift typically (10% to 20% as compared to 70% to 75%) but its equally unpredictable and equally political. In both cases the % formula sounds fairly predictable on paper, but calculating the lift is a mugs game.

  • Bill Lee

    @neil21 // Jul 25, 2013 at 9:30 am #1

    I disagree with the idea of models as they don’t fuly compare with a street level view, in the pouring rain on an adjacent sidewalk.
    Lets require quick frame scaffold and balloon skin full sized “models” so we can get a better view.
    It has been done in the area for several storey residences sometimes.

    And re: your reference to Charles Marohn of the Minnesota planning mafia
    The blog is called Strong Towns Journal
    http://www.strongtowns.org/journal/
    (Statement of mission link: strongtowns.org/quantifying-strong-towns )

    And while we are on about outside reading

    I see that “Rebel Cities” (2012), “Paris, Capital, Of Modernity” (2003), “Social Justice and the City” (1973, revised 2009) and “Critical Reader” (2006) among others by David Harvey are downloadable as TXT or PDF files free at ScribD.com (You might trade, and upload random city council memo PDFs for download “credit”)

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    The City only can make money from developers when they rezone. If the developer is held to the zoning bylaw no amenity payment is required.

    Jonathan Baker 9

    The unwanted result of this practice—from the perspective of the neighbourhood—is that the directions specified in the neighbourhood plans must be exceeded.

    Only projects that ‘break’ the zoning and the plan qualify for CACs. Council approves a community plan, then turns around and approves a CD-1 re-zoning that by definition must be something other than what was envisioned in the community-vetted document.

    Three “wink-wink; nudge-nudge” tower areas were included in the Mount Pleasant Community Plan (Rize, Kingsgate Mall, IGA on Main). However, as we have been witnessing for 16 months at the Rize site, this practice delivers in fuzzy plans and neighbourhood indignation.

    Thanks Randy and Jonathan for shedding light into areas where myself and others lack expertise.

  • Silly Season

    What a mess of a merry-go-round.

    Here we have developers, on one hand, saying that they need predictability and surety in order to figure out fixed costs for their projects. Is it really them alone who push up the FSR’s? On the other hand, don’t many of them also buy locations looking for that much valued change in zoning (from city halls, everywhere)?

    Civic governments, then use unpredictabilty (so throw out all those Neighbourhood Plans, people!) in order to ratchet up the ‘donations’ they can get from developers to add to their general revenues (and pet projects, that they then claim THEY have built!). Tony Soprano would be so proud.

    Who loses?

    The taxpayers, who always sit outside the glassed walls of City Planning/Development and have nary a real say in final outcomes.

    The same people who must deal with higher housing costs, and density numbers that seems to change from definition to defintion (or changes due to the current revenue needs at City Hall) . The same people who have no assurance that monies from develoments in their neighbourhood will provide them any attributable, site specific ammenities.

    Here’s a solution: build surety into the system. Put on your big boy/girl pants and DESIGN this city, according to best practices in mixed housing (heights and density) and how they could could accomodate neighbourhoods—and vice versa. Have a 50 year plan for ‘gentle’ upgrowth/rezoning. But don’t piddle this opportunity away.

    The fact that we seem to be throwing up buildings willy nilly (height,/density/unit size) lead me to several conclusions: we are in panic mode with regards to civic revenue, so let’s latch on to all the investor money we can grab so as to stay afloat in the short -term ( and of no use as long term strategy). AND that we have absolutley NO CLUE about affordability or jobs for people who would LIKE to pay thier taxes into their communities.

    (On the revenues side: I want our civic and provincial governements to push the Feds into ensuring that everyone who has a property here AND enjoys the benefits of our health and education system are required to contribute some of their world wide income to the national income tax base—not just the local property tax base. And for those who are only part-timers here from outside Canada, or who hold property only as investments, I think a property tax of 3-5x thegoing rate would be fair. Or, if you are a non-resident, but hold a property, that you pay capital gains when you go to sell the property. Done in many other places—hello, Scottsdale, Palm Springs, etc, so no whining that we al merrily use others systems the way people use ours).

    Decide on zoning designations, NOW. This will give us all an opportunity to know what could be coming down and possibly (ha) end property speculation that helps drive up prices/’CAC’ in the long term.

    Instead of these STIR cookie cutter tower monstrosities that sprout up like nuclear mushrooms on steroids throughout the city, creating upset and constantly pitting neighbourhoods against planning/politicians/developers, create the conditions where neighbourhoods see and participate in LOGICAL plans that show–in advance–the possibilities.

    There MUST be mixed housing types—even at the transit hubs/intersections which are now being used more as an excuse to build UP rather than as a reason to build BETTER.

    Now back to your original q, Frances.

    I don’t mind if the ‘contributions” a developer gives to CoV is announced.

    But not before my name as a taxpayer goes on a burnished plaque on a patch of sidewalk, or politicians stop implying that the taxpayer money they use comes from them!

  • neil21

    @Bill

    I imagine a 3D model in your web browser that you could walk around. Place yourself on the sidewalk. Mess with the time of day, and sky colour (maybe even weather, not sure about the processing power required).

    I hacked this together in a couple of days, but don’t have anything like the skills to finish it up. I’ll need to describe it all better and get it Kickstarted I suppose http://neil21.github.io/Formr/formr.html

    Anyone know any three.js gurus?

  • David

    If it was true that CACs were being passed on to homebuyers, then final sale prices of units should be equal between projects that were rezoned and paid a CAC versus projects that were built under current zoning and did not pay a CAC. I can tell you that there is no price difference between those two types of projects. Both projects will charge market averages largely based on location and level of finish.

  • Randy Chatterjee

    Dead on, Silly Season 13! Markets require transparency (of price and product), and this current system is anything but. Did no one notice that central planning died with the Soviet Union 25 years ago! Nice ideas on ways to reduce housing speculation and increase affordability. See also: http://www.vancouversun.com/opinion/op-ed/Help+rental+market+Impose+vacancy/8421480/story.html
    Niel21 14 – Your 3D drawing works (in Firefox), and we can certainly do this with Google Earth and Sketch-Up at even finer detail and without having to recreate any of what is already there.

    Thank you for the correction, Ian 10. I suppose few write about Toronto’s Section 37 since the payments are, well, more reasonable. This is of course in the eye of the beholder, since 10-20% is the entire profit margin of an average development in most of the world.

    Early in my previous post, I also mistyped “land lift” as “land life”–a Freudian slip perhaps as land values seem to have a life of their own here.

    I also made another mistake in not answering Frances’ real question: how to thank the developers. We need to apologize, not thank them. We also need to apologize to all of the recent buyers who suffered from this CAC “tax” passed onto them. Per Silly Season, we all need ‘contributor plaques.’

    That CACs are passed along to buyers is of course a given, against which no economist would argue, but its real and fully-encompassing magnitude is not clear.

    Warren (5) is correct that on their own, the CAC amounts are trivial. The Rize’s assessed $6.25 million CAC plus $538,000 public art “contribution”, or $6.8 million, amounts to just over $20,000 per unit (336 currently proposed), or about a 3% surcharge on average.

    However, what is happening behind the scenes of this CAC–and this is a thousand-act play staged over 5-10 years–is first the opacity of the “real” zoning of the site. This uncertainty generates significant speculative payoff from successfully gaming, or maneuvering, the system. Of course, influence peddling has a huge cost: at least $4 million every three years in Vancouver. Needless to say, every savvy seller–such as single family lot owners on Cambie Street pricing their lots at $4 million–knows about land assembly and rezoning. So, land costs get bid up, hugely, and just about everywhere.

    In the case of the Rize development, how do you price:
    – a full-time talent like Chris Vollan for several years, expenses, and support staff,
    – a year-long pop-up retail site,
    – inserting an actual drawing of the proposed development into the Council-approved Community Plan without anyone seeing it in advance,
    – hundreds of thousands of dollars in advertising in collateral, radio, print, and social media,
    – now almost three years of Acton-Ostrey’s, PWL’s, and dozens of other site consultants’ time to come up with multiple complete drawing packages and engineering studies,
    – all of those “artistic” (fantastical? misleading?) as-built renderings apparently done by yet another consultant,
    – at least a dozen Open Houses and community presentations, 7 days and nights in Council, and at least a day at the UDP and another at the DPB, and all with multiple consultants and principals present,
    – informants and influencers at City Planning and community meetings,
    – and much, much more!

    There has got to be a LOT of profit in any project, AND DEEP POCKETS FOR MANY YEARS, to get through the Vancouver rezoning maze.

    The apparent $20,000 per unit of CAC frictional payments in this zoning-optional, air-rights-for-sale development approval system may well be closer to $60-80,000 per unit, approaching the bare cost of construction. Yes, that is how truly insane this CAC tax is!

    And the worse thing of all is that the Rize does not yet have its rezoning in hand, 17 months after Council approval. With no enactment to date, the site is still C-3A, despite ALL that water under the bridge. #nightmare

  • Silly Season

    @Randy Chatterjee,

    I really appreciate your very thorough expose of what happens at the developer level and the inner workings at Planning/City Hall with regards to this cluster pluck.

    The politicians are of course both afraid and contemptuous of process—and always seemingly on the lookout for friendly contributors they can shake dow…er…encourage for ‘more’.

    It is a ridiculous process all way round and costs the economy in every single way.

  • Jon Petrie

    Worth reading — the West Van experience with CAC’s:
    Amenities math questioned: Resident argues municipality is shortchanging itself on payments

    http://www.nsnews.com/business/Amenities+math+questioned/8670457/story.html

  • Ryan

    I agree, maybe if the public was a little bit more aware of just how much development fees pay for, they would be a little less inclined towards severe nimbyism.

  • Julien

    Yes. Council should be recognizing the contributors of CAC’s. The home buyers. Time to order the slab cake and orange drink and throw a block party.
    If the developers want recognition, why not ask the councillors and mayor to recognize the altruistic contributions of the developers to their campaigns. Now that I could support. Oh and the token park bench and flower box that passes for a park, built on squatted land, another community contribution that goes unappreciated.

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    To add a twist to the conversation there is an ideology of laissez-fair lying thinly veiled behind the CD-1 re-zonings.

    By taking the planning process, and the community vision and voice, effectively off the table the industry gets to do pretty much what they want.

    Some propose it as unfettered capitalism.

  • Tessa

    Oh those generous developers, it’s so nice of them to pay the fees that they are required by law to pay. Sure are going the extra mile, aren’t they?

  • PW

    Interesting this issue is coming up now. In normal times these costs are simply passed on to the buyers. But today, with all objective measures showing prices well beyond the average buyer, and a dwindling number of speculators anxious to take up the slack, developers are going to have to absorb more of the cost.
    If they are losing money they could always stop development. But the City, needing development revenue almost as much as the developers, does not want that. So, despite a stagnant economy, we must urgently continue to build and must urgently go bigger and higher.
    I wonder how an economist who thinks in terms of incentives would view this. It seems to me the incentive to the City is to go as big as possible. That way, with the CAC revenue, they can appear to be doing great things and Councillor Reimer can tweet to her followers how much social good they are creating.
    I’ll make an outrageous prediction that within a decade thousands of the condos (in reality, lightly regulated derivative investments) being built today will be picked up at huge discounts by vulture funds. They will then hit the rental market creating a glut of rental properties.

  • Frank Ducote

    PW@22 – your first paragraph is quite astute. Depending on market conditions, there are three potential payers of DCCs and CACs – the property vendor, the developer and “in normal times” the purchaser. I guess a fourth option is all of the above.

    It is by no means always a clear cut outcome that the buyer always pays this additional cost.

  • Cheezwiz

    Oh those poor, poor unappreciated developers. My heart bleeds for them. By tossing a some extra dough the City’s way, they basically get carte-blanche to build whatever they want wherever they want regardless of neighborhood wants and needs.

  • Bill Lee

    And how is this “credit to…” to be delivered?

    Passing the ex-gas station “world’s largest” collection of toothpick trees soi-disant “verger” (orchard) while riding north on the Main bus early in the morning this week, I saw the placard on the wire fence noting sponsors, including Concord-Pacific ( Xiéhé tàipíngyáng 協和太平洋 ) [ Peaceful^2 ] and immediately thought how bad their reputation can become.

    Look at Bosa Properties, developers of the End-of-False-Creek towers, and how they changed their development names quite often, Bosa, Boffo (soon to be pariah in DTES) etc.

    And really the land speculators use of short-term numbered companies makes a joke out of attribution.

    Do they want loud credit, or just notice of the “extra” fees they pay for land speculation?

  • F.H.Leghorn

    We already have a shining monument to the development industry. His name is Gregor Robertson.

  • Bill Lee

    And should they take the “credit” for that “world’s largest” verger orchard on contaminated ground when it is all a PR push to sanctify(?) a tax dodge.

    Under the City of Vancouver’s tax classifications, the property would normally be designated class six: “business or other,” with a taxation rate of 1.75 per cent. The presence of the urban farm re-designates the lot to class eight, or “recreation and non-profit,” which lowers the tax rate to 0.56 — less than a third of the original rate.
    Thus the vague act of greenness is stealing from the City’s income, as is SOLEFoods, Dunbar and 40th, 70 West Hastings, 117 East Hastings the Hastings Temporary Garden 2500 East Hastings on the latest failed London Drugs proposal, and several others around the city.

    Why don’t they open their full books instead and let us read the profits (or loss) each month.

  • Lewis N. Villegas

    …the City, needing development revenue almost as much as the developers, does not want that. So, despite a stagnant economy, we must urgently continue to build and must urgently go bigger and higher.

    PW 23

    I find this to be PWs more telling statement. Earlier today I was having a chat with two other people replying on this thread about just this point.

    We were recalling for each other how the largest and most ostentatious buildings always seem to come just before the market crashes. The Chrysler Building in NYC before the 1929 crash; and the Marine building in our city, more or less an exact contemporary. Paid for in cash if memory serves—Major Matthews reprints a letter from the architects specifying this and other facts on that last piece of urban fabric to go before the bottom fell out.

    Of course, these are also signs writ large all over the globe that we are changing paradigm from the megastructure dominated (and benefiting) by the very circumscribed few, back to the vernacular that can be built and enjoyed by everyone.

    The objects of permanence we are striving to build are not the buildings in themselves, authored by the few, but rather the neighbourhoods and public places accented to by the community as a whole, and sites of true and meaningful human interactions.

    PS

    More and more I am reading our blog hosts slowing down in the pace of posting stories about the city as the mask coming down to reveal—somewhat to our surprise—that even she has been taken aback by the failure of the Gregor Robertson regime to live up to its hype.